Imatges de pàgina
PDF
EPUB

|

Spain and Naples; to Austria, in 1766; to Bavaria, in 1768; to the noblesse of Franconia, Suabia, and the Upper and Lower Rhine, in 1769; to the Protestant Cantons of Switzerland, in 1771; and to Holland, in 1773. In Louis XVI.'s reign, other treaties of the same kind were made with Saxony, Poland, Portu

in 1315 (compare the Recueil des Ordonnances du Louvre, tom. i. p. 610), but, as it turned out, for his own reign only. Exemption from the operation of the Droit d'Aubaine was granted in 1364 by Charles V. in favour of persons born within the states of the Roman Church. Louis XI., in 1472, granted a similar exemption to strangers dwelling at Tou-gal, and the United States. The abolition louse; and Francis I., in 1543, to strangers resident in Dauphiné. Charles IX., in 1569, allowed exemption from it to merchant-strangers frequenting the fairs at Lyon. Henry IV., in 1608, granted exemption to the subjects of the republic of Geneva. Louis XIV., in 1702, to the subjects of the Duke of Lorraine. (Chasles, Dict. tom. i. pp. 265, 267.) The Swiss and the Scotch of the king's guard had been exempted by King Henry II. (Bacquet, Traité de Droit d'Aubaine, p. i. c. 7.)

Partial exemptions from the Droit d'Aubaine were frequently conventional, and formed clauses in treaties, which stipulated for reciprocal relief to the subjects of the contracting parties; these exemptions, it is probable, continued no longer than the peace which the treaty had procured, and some related to moveable goods only.

In the treaty of commerce between England and France, in 1606, the Jus Albinatûs, as it is termed, was to be abandoned as related to the English: "Ita ut in posterum aliquo modo jure Albinatûs fisco addici non possint." (Rym. Fœd. tom. xvi. p. 650.) Letters-patent of Louis XIV., in 1669, confirmed in the parliament of Grenoble in 1674, exempted the Savoyards; and this exemption was confirmed by the treaty of Utrecht, in 1713. The inhabitants of the Catholic cantons of Switzerland were exempted by treaty in 1715. The particulars of numerous other conventional treaties are recorded in M. Gaschon's work, in the speech of the Duc de Levis already rcferred to, and in the Rapport' from the Marquis de Clermont-Tonnerre to the French Chamber of Peers, printed in the 'Moniteur' for 1819, pp. 96-98.

Louis XV. granted exemptions, first to Denmark and Sweden; then, in the treaty called the "Family Compact," to

of the Aubaine, as it related to Russia, was a distinct article of another treaty; and, finally, by letters-patent, dated January, 1787, its abolition was pronounced in favour of the subjects of Great Britain.

The National Assembly, by laws dated August 6, 1790, and April 13, 1791 (confirmed by a constitutional act, 3rd of September, 1791), abolished the Droit d'Aubaine entirely. It was nevertheless re-established in 1804. (Moniteur for 1818, p. 551.) The treaty of Paris, 30th of April, 1814, confirmed the exemptions from the Aubaine as far as they were acknowledged in existing treaties. The final abolition of the Droit d'Aubaine, as already mentioned, was proposed by the Duc de Levis, April 14, 1818, and passed into a law, July 14, 1819, which confirmed the laws of 1790 and 1791. Foreigners can now hold lands in France by as firm a tenure as native subjects.

The Droit d'Aubaine was occasionally relaxed, by the kings of France, upon minor considerations. In the very early part of the 14th century, an exemption was obtained by the University of Paris for its students, as an encouragement to their increasing numbers. Charles V. granted the privilege in 1364 to such Castilian mariners as wished to trade with France. In 1366 he extended it to Italian merchants who traded to Nismes. The fairs of Champagne were encouraged in the same manner; and exemp tions to traders were also granted by Charles VIII. and Louis XI. Francis I. granted the exemption to foreigners who served in his army; Henry IV. to those who drained the marshes cr worked in the tapestry-looms. Louis XIV. extended the exemption to the particular manufacturers who worked at Beauvais and the Gobelins; then to the glass

manufacturers who had come from Venice; in 1662, to the Dunkirkers, whose town he had acquired by purchase from England; and, lastly, to strangers settled at Marseille, that city having become the entrepôt of products from the Levant.

Ambassadors and persons in their suite were not subject to the Droit d'Aubaine; nor did it affect persons accidentally passing through the country.

That the Droit d'Aubaine existed in Italy, in the papal states, in the eleventh, twelfth, and thirteenth centuries, seems established by Muratori, Antiq. Ital. Medii Ævi,' fol. Mediol. 1739, tom. ii. col. 14.

An extensive treatise on the Droit d'Aubaine has been already quoted in the works of Jean Bacquet, avocat de Roi en la Chambre de Thresor, fol. Paris, 1665. See also 'Mémoires du Droit d'Aubaine,' at the end of M. Dupuy's 'Traitez touchant le Droits du Roy très-Chrestien,' fol. Par. 1655; and the Coutumes du Balliage de Vitry en Perthois,' par Estienne Durand, fol. Châlons, 1722, p. 254. But the most comprehensive view of this law, in all its bearings, will be found in the Répertoire Universel et Raisonné de Jurisprudence,' par M. Merlin, 4to. Paris, 1827, tom. i. p. 523,

art.

"Aubaine;" tom. vii. p. 416, art. "Heritier." The Moniteurs of 1818 and 1819 contain abstracts of the discussions while the abolition was passing through the two Chambers at Paris. See the latter year, pp. 314, 315, 509, 510, 728, 729. The chief passages in the former year have been already quoted.

AUCTION, a method employed for the sale of various descriptions of property. This practice originated with the Romans, who gave it the descriptive name of auctio, an increase, because the property was publicly sold to him who would offer most for it. In more modern times a different method of sale has been sometimes adopted, to which the name of auction is equally, although not so correctly applied. This latter method, which is called a Dutch auction, thus indicating the local origin of the practice, consists in the public offer of property at a price beyond its value, and then gra

dually lowering or diminishing that price until some one consents to become the purchaser. An auction is defined by 19 Geo. III. c. 56, § 3, and 42 Geo. III. c. 93, § 3, to be "a sale of any estate, goods, or effects whatever, by outcry, knocking down of hammer, by candle, by lot, by parcel, or by any other mode of sale at auction, or whereby the highest bidder is deemed to be the purchaser." According to the revenue laws, every auction at which property is put up and bidden for is a "sale," so as to raise the charge of duty, without regard to the subsequent completion of the purchase by the delivering possession or actual transfer of the thing sold. There must, however, be an actual competition as to price, or biddings, or an invitation made to a competition of biddings, and if a single bidding is made the liability to pay auction duty is incurred.

The sale by auction was used by the Romans for the disposal of military spoils, and was conducted sub hasta, that is, under a spear, which was stuck into the ground upon the occasion. This expression was continued, and sales were declared to be conducted sub hastâ in cases where other property was sold by auction, and probably after the spear was dispensed with. The phrase "asta pubblica" is still used by the Italians to signify a public sale or auction: the expression is, "vendere all' asta pubblica," or "vendere per subasta." The auctio transferred to the purchaser the Quiritarian ownership of the thing that he bought.

At the present day persons are sometimes invited to a "sale by the candle,” or "by the inch of candle." The origin of this expression arose from the employment of candles as the means of measuring time, it being declared that no one lot of goods should continue to be offered to the biddings of the persons who were present for a longer time than would suffice for the burning of one inch of candle; as soon as the candle had wasted to that extent, the then highest bidder was declared to be the purchaser.

In sales by auction, the assent of the buyer is given by his bidding, while the assent of the seller is signified by the fall of the auctioneer's hammer;

and until this declaration has been made, the bidder is at liberty to withdraw his bidding.

It is a common practice for the owner of property offered for sale by auction to reserve to himself the privilege of bidding, and, as it is termed, buying in his goods, if the price offered by others should not suit him. As late as the time of Lord Mansfield, private biddings at auctions were considered to be illegal. In the present day, however, they are not only allowed by the law, but the legislature has so far recognised the propriety of the practice, that in cases where the property has been bought in either by the proprietor or by his declared agent, who is in general the auctioneer, no auction duty is chargeable; but if bought in by the owner personally, he must do so openly, and if bought in by an agent, he must do so by authority of a written notice. When a buyer-in afterwards becomes a purchaser, the transaction is narrowly looked after by the officers of the revenue, and the auctioneer's bond is liable to be put in suit if the auction duty has been fraudulently evaded.

It has been laid down that the buyer of goods at an auction cannot be held to the performance of his contract in cases where he was the only bonâ fide bidder at the sale, and where public notice was not given of the intention of the owner of the goods to bid, even though his agent was authorized to bid only to a certain sum. This rule is intended to act as a protection to purchasers against the practice commonly resorted to by disreputable auctioneers, of employing persons to make mock biddings with the view of raising the price by their apparent competition: the persons thus employed are aptly called puffers. In many large towns, and more especially in London, many persons make a trade of holding auctions of inferior and ill-made goods; persons called barkers are generally placed by them at the door to invite strangers to enter, and puffers are always employed, who bid more for the articles than they are worth, and thus entice the unwary. Many ineffectual attempts have been made to put a stop to these practices.

The auctioneer is considered the agent |

of both parties, vendor and purchaser. In the language of the judges in a late case, "a bidder, by his silence when the hammer falls, confers an authority on the auctioneer to execute the contract on his behalf." He can therefore bind the parties by his signature according to the requisition of the Statute of Frauds, which renders it necessary in contracts of sale of "lands or any interest in or concerning them," and of goods above the value of 10l., and that some "note or memorandum should be signed by the parties or their agents lawfully authorized." Such signature is now held sufficient even in an action brought by the auctioneer against the vendor in his own name. It has been doubted therefore, whether a bidder may not retract (in cases within the statute) at any time before the actual written entry. The auctioneer also stands in the situation of a stakeholder of the deposited part of the purchase-money, which he is not at liberty to part with till the sale has been carried into effect; and he cannot, at least after notice, discharge himself by paying over the amount to the vendor. It has been settled by a late decision that he is not liable for any interest on, or advantage which he may make from, the money in his hands. In this respect his situation differs from that of a mere agent, and also from that of one of the contracting parties (the vendor), from whom "interest is recoverable in the nature of damages for a breach of the original contract on the part of the vendor, by whose failure to make a good title the vendee has for a time lost the use of his money." (Mr. Justice James Parke.) An auctioneer (like any other agent and trustee concerned in the sale of property) is forbidden to buy on his own account; and when he sells without disclosing the name of his principal, an action will lie against himself for damages on the breach of contract.

The conditions of sale constitute the terms of the bargain, and purchasers are bound to take notice of them. The late Lord Ellenborough said that "a little more fairness on the part of auctioneers in framing particulars would avoid many inconveniences. There is always either

a suppression of the fair description of the premises, or something stated which does not belong to them; and in favour of justice, considering how little knowledge the parties have of the thing sold, much more particularity and fairness might be expected." The conditions usually contain a provision that "any error or mis-statement shall not vitiate the sale, but that an allowance shall be made for it in the purchase-money." But this clause is held only to guard against unintentional errors, and not to compel a purchaser to complete the contract if he has been designedly misled.

loom, and in lots of the price of twenty pounds and upwards," were exempted from the payment of duty.

The produce of the whale and seal fisheries enjoyed an equal exemption, as well as elephants' teeth, palm oil, drugs, and other articles for the use of dyers: also mahogany and other woods used by cabinet-makers, and all goods imported by way of merchandise from any British colony in America, the same being of the growth, produce, or manufacture of such colony, and sold by the original importer within twelve months from the time of importation.

by the sheriff for the benefit of creditors in execution of judgment, and bankrupts' effects sold by assignees, were not held liable to the payment of auction-duty; which last species of exemptions was made upon the principle of not aggra

Neither was any duty The duties that were levied upon chargeable upon property sold by order goods sold by public auction were not of the courts of Chancery or Exchequer; charged according to any uniform scale. nor on any sale made by the East India Sheep's wool of British growth, sold for or Hudson's Bay Company; nor by order the benefit of the growers, or of persons of the Commissioners of Customs, Exwho had purchased directly from the cise, or other government boards of comgrowers, were subject to a duty of two-missioners. In like manner, sales made pence for every twenty shillings of the purchase-money. This duty produced less than 207. in the whole of the United Kingdom, in 1842. Freehold, copyhold, or leasehold estates, whether in land or buildings; shares in the joint-stock of corporate or chartered companies; re-vating their losses to innocent sufferers. versionary interest in any of the public funds; and ships or vessels-were liable to pay sevenpence for every twenty shillings: household furniture, horses, carriages, pictures, books, and the like kinds of personal property, were made to pay one shilling for every twenty shillings of the purchase-money. (45 Geo. III. c. 30.) Bonds granted under a local paving act, and charged upon certain premises, were held to be an interest in land, and as such subject to the lower rate of duty. Upon this principle dock-bonds, gaswork shares, railroad shares, canal shares, bridge shares, shares in a news room or library, pews in a church or chapel, policies, bonds, and other securities which created or conveyed any interest in land, tenements, or hereditaments, were charged only with the lower duty of sevenpence in the pound. (Bateman On the Excise, p. 332, ed. 1843.) But many exceptions were made by the legislature when imposing these duties. "Piece-goods, wove or fabricated in this kingdom, which shall be sold entire in the piece or quantity, as taken from the

Goods distrained for non-payment of tithes were also exempt. For the same reason, goods damaged by fire, or wrecked or stranded, which were sold for the benefit of insurers, were not charged with duty. Wood, coppice, the produce of mines or quarries, cattle, corn, stock or produce of land, might be sold by auction free of duty while they continued on the lands producing the same. The exemption only extended to the unmanufactured produce of land, and did not include cheese, butter, flour, &c.; and the stock of a nurseryman would be liable to the duty, the exemption being confined strictly to agricultural produce. By virtue of a Treasury warrant issued in 1822, auction-duty was not charged on the sale of property of foreign ministers to the court of Great Britain on their leaving England. The effects of officers and soldiers dying in her Majesty's service might be sold by auction by a non-commissioned officer or soldier, without incurring auction-duty; and in 1839 this exemption was extended to the effects of deserters.

In case the sale of an estate were declared void, through defect of title, the duty that had been paid might be claimed again within three months after the time when the defect had been discovered. It was very common to stipulate that the buyer should pay the amount of duty in addition to the sums bid by him.

The duty on sales by auction in Great Britain was first imposed during the American war, in 1777 (17 Geo. III. c. 50), and in Ireland in 1797. In the last twenty years the amount of goods sold in the United Kingdom on which auction-duty was charged has varied from 10,148,571. in 1825, to 6,326,4817. in 1831; and the amount of the duty has been as high as 328,8331. and as low as 218,0841. In 1840 the duty was 320,058. charged on sales amounting to 8,720,9851. In 1841 the duty amounted to 314,0677.; 296,964% in 1842, and 284,9167. in 1843. In 1842 it appears, from a table in M'Culloch's Dictionary, that the duty arose from the several articles enumerated below:

[blocks in formation]

260,259 19,841 16,863

During the sitting of the Commissioners of Excise Inquiry they were waited upon by seven of the most eminent auctioneers in London, who represented that the duty of sevenpence in the pound, equivalent to three per cent. on the amount of the purchase-money, had for some time past caused a rapid and universal decrease in the number of actual sales by auction. One auctioneer stated that, in consequence of all sales of property in Chancery being exempt from auction-duty, "many bills are filed in the Court of Chancery, when the property is large, for no other purpose than saving the auction-duty, notwithstanding the great amount of law

|

expenses." Another of the deputation complained of the duty as "an unequal, oppressive, and impolitic tax," and suggested that instead thereof "there should be an additional ad valorem duty of one per cent. upon all transfers of real property, conveyed by deed or written instrument, whether sold by auction or private contract." The Commissioners in their report (twelfth) state that the auction-duty is open to great objections, and should be "wholly repealed as soon as practicable." They conceive that this impolitic tax has been "borne with patience solely in con sequence of the exemptions, either direct or indirect, which the more powerful interests of the country, manufacturing and agricultural, have succeeded in obtaining from its operation." In consequence of these representations the auction-duties were repealed in 1845, and the recommendation of the Commissioners adopted.

The Romans imposed taxes on the produce of certain sales, and it may be presumed on all such sales, whether public or private. In the time of Augustus (Dion Cassius, lv. 31), a tax of two per cent. was imposed on the produce of sales of slaves. This tax is spoken of by Tacitus (Ann. xiii. 31) as being then a tax of four per cent. (if the reading is right). In the time of Nero it was enacted that the seller should pay the tax, from which it may be inferred that the buyer had hitherto paid it. The buyers of slaves were generally Romans, and the sellers were foreign dealers. This change in the mode of paying the duty was called a remission of the tax, but as Tacitus observes, it was a remission in name, not in effect, for the tax was still paid by the purchaser in the shape of a higher price. After the civil wars, and during the time of Augustus, a tax of one per cent. was imposed on the produce of sales by auction at Rome. In the time of Tiberius the tax was reduced to one-half per cent. (Tacit., Ann. i. 78, ii. 42); but after the death of Sejanus it was again raised to one per cent. Caligula (Suetonius, Calig. 16) remitted the tax again, by first reducing it to onehalf per cent., and then remitting it altogether. (Dion Cassius, lviii. 16, and the note of Reimarus.)

AUCTIONEER, a person whose pro

« AnteriorContinua »